Market Bubbles & The Perception Of Time -Part II

GLOBALCAPITAL INTERNATIONAL LIMITED, a company

incorporated in England and Wales (company number 15236213),

having its registered office at 4 Bouverie Street, London, UK, EC4Y 8AX

Accessibility | Terms of Use | Privacy Policy | Modern Slavery Statement | Event Participant Terms & Conditions

Market Bubbles & The Perception Of Time -Part II

Risk And Return In Intrinsic Time

Neoclassical finance deals with continuous time, but stocks do not trade continuously; and opportunities to profit depend on the frequency and volume with which one can trade.

The trading frequency *i of a stock, the number of trades per second, implicitly determines an intrinsic-time scale *i for that stock, the time ticked off by an imaginary clock whose units (dimensionless 'ticks') measure the passing of trades.

During the late 1990s, day-traders who made rapid round-trip trades in stocks are said to have controlled as much as 15% of the daily volume of technology stocks. We model their behavior by assuming that they focus on the return earned per tick of intrinsic time rather than per second (or month) of calendar time.

Intrinsic-time speculators describe the stock with the intrinsic-time doublet (Mi, (sum)i), where Mi is the expected return of stock i per tick and (sum)i is the stock's intrinsic-time volatility, the square root of the variance of the returns per tick. In contrast, traditional calendar-time investors characterize the stock by the calendar-time doublet (µi, *i).

There is a simple relation between these two doublets. Since a stock i's trading frequency *i is the number of intrinsic-time ticks in one calendar second, an increment *i of intrinsic time is related to an increment t of calendar time via

Since independent mean returns and variances add up over successive ticks, we find that

and

so that

We now take the view of a short-term day trader who lives in intrinsic time and cares only about the passage of ticks rather than seconds. We assume that day traders, except for their distorted sense of time, are otherwise rational and subscribe to an intrinsic-time version of the risk-return principle above, namely:

 

Two portfolios with the same perceived irreducible intrinsic-time risk should have the same expected intrinsic-time return.

 

All the relations between risk and return that we derived in Part 1 will therefore continue to hold after we transform them as follows:

All the relations between risk and return that we derived in Part 1 will therefore continue to hold after we transform them as follows:

Applying the transformation of equation 3.5 to equation 2.3, we obtain the relationship

where * is the dimensionless intrinsic-time Sharpe ratio, and *B is the trading frequency of the riskless overnight bond, typically of order one trade per day.

We can rewrite equation 3.6 as

where

is the temperature of the stock and is a measure of the perceived riskiness of the stock for speculators. Equation 3.7 states that expected excess return is proportional to temperature.

 

If you can diversify over many uncorrelated stocks, then * = 0 and,

so that the calendar-time expected return for a stock i exceeds the riskless rate if *i > *B.

 

The intrinsic-time version of the Capital Asset Pricing Model is obtained by applying the transformation of equation 3.5 to equation 2.8, yielding

If the riskless rate r is negligible, then all profit and loss comes from volatility and equation 3.9 simplifies to

Such speculators will expect a short-term return proportional to the traditional beta of the stock, but enhanced by the square root of the ratio of the stock's trading frequency to the trading and frequency of the market.

 

Market Bubbles

The interaction between intrinsic-time speculators and calendar-time investors can cause a bubble. Assume r = 0 and consider a stock with trading frequency *. Speculators will expect the return of equation 3.7, namely

Suppose that this return is realized as a consequence of their trading activity.

Calendar-time-based investors, following equation 2.3, will expect a return.

Observing the realized return µI, these investors will observe the excess return.

Suppose that this excess return attracts an additional number of calendar-time traders per second whose number is proportional to , so that

The last equality, expressed in terms of the intrinsic-time volatility (sum), follows from equation 3.3.

For large calendar time t, the first term on the right-hand-side of equation 4.4 dominates, and

From equation 4.1, µI = *(sum)* * *(sum)exp(**(sum)t). The stock's expected return grows exponentially with time and its price grows at the bubble rate (exp(**(sum)t)).

This growth rate described an unsustainable bubble. As the market runs out of calendar time speculators to keep driving the temperature up, the bubble must burst.

 

This week's Learning Curve was written by Emanuel Derman, who recently retired from Goldman Sachs where he was a managing director and head of the quantitative risk strategies group in the firm-wide risk department in New York. He can be contacted at emanuel@ederman.com.

Related articles

Gift this article